Terrorist Financing Innovation in the Crime-Terror Nexus
“Follow the money, target the money, kill the money” - Meir Dagan (1945-2016)
By Zachariah Parcels
Introduction
Terrorists cannot symmetrically confront modern States. Instead, terrorists violently struggle by using or threatening to use violence against civilians to achieve political aims.[1] Befitting the definition by Ganor and the “Doubtful Terrorism Proper” designations by Enders and colleagues, there have been 155,551 (as of 2020) terrorist attacks since 1970.[2] Yet, only spectacularly innovative terrorist attacks take nations by surprise by exploiting vulnerabilities in security apparatuses and inflicting high material, psychological, social, and emotional costs.[3] Albeit being an accessible and inexpensive means of violent political expression, terrorism really exemplifies disruptive innovation when it is sufficiently financed.[4] Though, money is needed more for logistics than operations.[5]
Amidst Hamas and Palestinian Islamic Jihad (PIJ) suiciding bombings, the late Meir Dagan’s (1945-2016) “Harpoon” unit, under Israel’s famed Mossad, realised this need, as did the US-led coalition against ISIS, to “follow the money, devalue the money, seize the money, and kill the money.”[6] Dagan subsequently influenced United States (U.S.) and international efforts, such as the Financial Action Task Force (FATF), to counter terrorism financing (CTF) and money laundering (AML).[7]
This paper adopts the follow-the-money directive by exploring the emergence of the crime-terror nexus, an increasingly salient terrorist financing conundrum not solely explained by existing typologies. By amalgamating terrorist financing and innovation typologies, we may begin to explore how and why terrorists began financing and associating with criminality. By illuminating Makarenko “Crime-Terror Nexus”[8] as a product and arena of terrorist financing innovation, this paper aspires to assist in Dagan’s directive to target the finances fuelling terror organisations.[9]
Money as the Lifeblood of Terror: Why do terrorists need money?
Through various methods of financing, AQ spent around $30 million annually in logistics prior to 9/11. This money financed recruitment, training camps, food, housing, armaments, training simulators (e.g., flight simulators), legitimate or forged documents, communication devices, and retirement pensions, among others. Terrorists’ annual budgets are in the hundreds of millions of dollars. The Provisional Irish Republican Army (PIRA) had a functional annual budget of around $15 million; Lebanon’s Hezbollah (“Party of God”) has an annual budget ranging up to $400 million; and Fuerzas Armadas Revolucionarias de Colombia (FARC) has an annual ranging from $100 million to $1 billion.[10] How do terrorists accumulate these millions, and what creates change in terror financing modus operandi?
Typologies of Terrorist Financing and Movement of Funds
The following sections elicit the empirical underpinnings of terrorist financing; the transition to illicit revenue streams, namely terrorist financing’s “Balloon Effect”;[11] the terrorist innovation typologies to explain terrorist financing adaptations; and, finally, how contemporary terrorist financing focuses on the crime-terror nexus. Crime-terror nexus refers to (a) the use of crime by terrorist groups as a source of funding;[12] and (b) formation of alliances between terrorist and criminal organisations.[13] Understanding why and how terrorists overtly criminalised financing and why and how terrorists innovate within the crime-terror nexus requires an analysis beyond terrorist financing literature.
Terrorist Financing
Financing Method Considerations
Terrorists are utility maximising, rational actors that weigh each action respective to their “political aims.” According to Freeman, terrorists consider six criteria that dictates the choice of financing method: quantity, security, reliability, simplicity, control, and legitimacy. Terrorists want sources that offer the largest quantity of money to be strong and effective.[14] For example, the illicit drug trade, crime-terror financing nexus’ largest contributor, is around $29.7 to $34.3 billion just in the European Union (EU).[15] As drugs warrant unwanted attention, terrorists must consider security. Reliability[16] depends on geography and demographics: to profit from drugs an organisation must be near the source (e.g., Hezbollah and marijuana), located on a trafficking route (e.g., PKK and heroin), or have access to enough users. Terrorists desire financial control rather than solely external sponsorship who may question the control of members and operations. According to Freeman, terrorists prefer simplistic financing methods that require less tacit knowledge, such as petty theft and kidnap-for-ransom; these methods require less skill than elaborate drug trafficking operations.[17] Lastly, terrorists require legitimacy to remain afloat; terrorists hesitantly use “illegitimate” sources, like the drug trade, and are undermined by methods to acquire personal wealth.[18]
Terrorism Financing Typologies
This section underlines terrorist financing’s empirical underpinnings, particularly from Michael Freeman, Peter Neuman, the FATF – a CTF and AML inter-governmental agency – and The Norwegian Defence Research Establishment (Forsvarets forskningsinstitutt).[19] Terrorist innovation literature has yet to merge with terrorism financing literature. This section enables the crime-terror nexus to be conceptually located with regards to terrorism financing.
Freeman catalogues terrorist financing into four general categories: state sponsorship, illegal activities, legal activities, and popular support.[20] Neuman asserts four factors that determine how terrorists finance: the group’s level of support; accessibility to illicit economies, namely ability to exploit pre-existing networks and collaborate with criminals; capacity to access legitimate revenue streams; and control over territory, as a reference to previous Islamic State (IS) successes.[21] However, the amalgam FATF and FFI typologies are pertinent and serve as a terrorism financing frame-of-reference.
FATF works to establish standards and promote effective legal, regulatory, and operational measures to threats to the international financial system’s integrity.[22] FATF lists private donations; abuse and misuse of non-profit organisations; criminal activity proceeds; extortion of local and diaspora populations and businesses; kidnapping for ransom; self-funding; legitimate business; and state sponsorship of terrorism as the principle means of financing terror.[23]
When analysing European jihadist cells’ financing, FFI’s Emilie Oftedal establishes a dichotomous typology that categorises and elaborates on FATF’s methods and techniques: there is “External Support” and “Self-Financing.”[24] External support refers to (1) popular support revenues streams, or charities, fundraising and individual donations; (2) terrorist support revenue streams, or international terrorist organisations and other cells/support networks; and (3) state sponsorship. Self-Financing refers to legal activities, namely personal assets, family assistance, business profits, loans, and credit card debt,[25] and illegal activities, such as thefts and robbery, illicit trade, forgery, other forms of fraud and other serious crimes (e.g., kidnapping and extortion).[26] This paper examines how terrorist organisations adaptation has caused a transition to self-financing, specifically illegal activities, and how terrorists have subsequently innovated to remain politically consequential.
The typologies offered by the FATF and FFI are descriptively useful. Accordingly, “illegal activities” denote terrorists’ involvement in criminal activity. Terrorists engage in petty theft, bank robberies, and other means of theft; the trade or taxation of illicit goods, such as drugs, stolen cars, and forged documents; pirating; kidnap-for-ransom; forgery; various other forms of fraud like credit card or welfare fraud; and smuggling of legal goods, such as cigarettes, oil, and conflict diamonds, among others.[27]
Movement of Funds
This paper does not address innovation in the movement of funds. It is theoretically relevant to understand the movement of money and how it pertains to terrorist financing but would require separate typologies and a unique approach to understand terrorist innovation in the movement of funds. Terrorists use various methods to move money: cash couriers, hawala and other informal transfer systems, formal banking, charities, cash-smuggling, money value transfer systems (MVTS) like Western Union (like Lashkar-e-Taiba, LeT), false invoicing, high value commodities, and trade-based money laundering.[28] Money laundering, namely masking proceeds of crime by moving value through trade transactions to legitimise illicit revenues, is a necessity for terrorists involved in illicit markets.[29] Internet and telecommunication technologies are also exploited by terrorists to transfer funds such as mobile non-bank led money services, electronic payment systems like PayPal or Skrill, and virtual currencies like Bitcoin.[30]
Insufficiencies of Terrorist Financing Typologies
Terrorism financing, like terrorists’ tactics, is a fluid phenomenon that adapts to pressures exhibited by CFT and AML forces, denoting the “Balloon Effect.” As in counterinsurgency (COIN), “the side that learns faster and adapts more rapidly—the better learning organization—usually wins.”[31] Moreover, this paper explores the learning competition that has culminated in and within the crime-terror nexus. Albeit being descriptively useful, terrorist financing typologies cannot explain or predict changes in financing modus operandi, particularly as it pertains to the crime-terror nexus. To further understand this learning competition, it is essential to understand terrorist innovation’s empirical underpinnings.
Conceptualising Terrorist Innovation[32]
Prior to 9/11, terrorism specialists like Bruce Hoffman who previously agreed with Adam Dolnik’s premise that “terrorists are conservative by nature”.[33] However, innovation, “the adoption of new patterns of behaviour,”[34] does occur. Joseph Schumpeter’s generalisable contribution to economic development serves as a basis to better understand innovation and terrorism innovation.[35] He viewed “development” as the process of “carrying out new combinations,” which is accomplished “in small steps” or “discontinuously.”[36] This process includes five major forms of “innovation” (“new combinations”): “the introduction of new goods… new methods of production… the opening of new markets… the conquest of new sources of supply… and the carrying out of a new organization of any industry.”[37] Further, this paper holds the Schumpeterian assertion of innovation as a phenomenon.
Terrorist innovation is empirically categorised into types, drivers, and levels.[38] Dolnik’s Understanding Terrorist Innovation, the first academic book on terrorist innovation, defines the latter as an “introduction of a new method or technology or the improvement of an already existing capability,”[39] incorporating development or discovery of new technologies or tactics and improving the use of technologies or tactics.[40] Yet, Martha Crenshaw seemingly accepts Dolnik’s definition but as “tactical innovation,” one of three types of terrorist innovation.[41]
Martha Crenshaw distinguishes between strategic, tactical, and organisational innovations in terrorist behaviour. Strategic innovations are strategic re-conceptualisations of terrorism, or “the way in which ends are related to means.”[42] Strategic innovations rarely occur and “involve a new goal and a new means of reaching it.”[43] Tactical innovations, echoing Dolnik, are “changes in method or operations… involve new weapons or targets and are much more frequent… [and] occur within strategies.”[44] Organisational innovations “involves changes in group structure and institutions” like the PIRA’s transition between 1976 to 1978 to clandestine, small, centralised, cellular organisation structure.[45]
Literature provides who and what drives terrorist innovation. Assaf Moghadam examined top-down, bottom-up, and integrative drivers of innovation in a case study on the 9/11 attacks.[46] Top-down innovation involves “entrepreneurial leadership” who impose or direct innovation from above, while bottom-up innovation stresses the role of low- and mid-level members.[47] Integrative drivers of innovation are “an innovation-abetting mechanism that depends on the confluence of both top-down and bottom-up forces”[48] like AQ’s “centralization of decision and decentralization of execution.”[49] Moghadam also discusses “independent jihadist entrepreneurs” as an example of how innovation may originate from outside the organisation. There are several key drivers of innovations: ideology, intergroup competition, problem-solving pressure, opportunity, and organisational capital.[50] Opportunity driver is particularly significant as it aligns with Loretta Napoleoni’s “New Economy of Terrorism,” namely post-Cold War “deregulation facilitated the merging of the terrorist economy with the illegal and criminal economies,”[51] which alludes to the crime-terror nexus. Further, Freeman’s six criteria may be generalised as potential innovation-inhibiting factors.
Lastly, Clayton Christensen and Cheung, Mahnken and Ross expound on terrorist innovation levels.[52] Christensen’s disruptive innovations disrupt and redefine existing markets by introducing usually simplistic, less expensive, and more accessible and convenient products.[53] In the context of terrorist, conventional forces have difficulties combatting terrorism as a “bottom of the market” disruptive innovation.[54] Cheung and colleagues contribute with seven levels of innovation, from duplicative imitation – copying existing innovations – to radical innovation – major technological or architectural breakthroughs.[55] Further, as illustrated by Theo Farrell, it is not “feasible or fruitful to draw too fine a distinction between adaptation and innovation.”[56]
As previously illuminated, changes in terrorist financing may be visualised as a learning competition.[57] Beyond types, drivers and levels of terrorist innovation, organisational learning is essential in understanding innovation in terrorist financing, specifically learning in the crime-terror nexus. According to a RAND study, organisational learning is composed of four component processes – acquisition, interpretation, distribution, and storage; “successful organisational learning requires a terrorist group to carry out all four of the component processes.”[58] Further, to measure a terrorist group’s learning capabilities, it is essential to understand explicit knowledge – “[knowledge] preserved in a physical form”[59] (e.g., instruction manuals) – and tacit knowledge – “more-abstract knowledge held by individuals.”[60]
Application of Theory:
Innovations in the Origin of the Nexus
Terrorism was predominantly state sponsored during the Cold War. Marxist groups (e.g., the Palestinian Front for the Liberation of Palestine or PFLP), were supported by the Soviet Union, North Korea, and Cuba; the U.S. supported the Afghan Mujahedin and Nicaraguan Contras; Arab States gave millions to the Palestinian Liberation Organisation (PLO); and Libya financed and supported, inter alia, PLO, PIRA, Euskadi Ta Askatasuna (ETA) and Baader-Meinhof.[61] Today, Iran and Syria support several organisations like Hezbollah and Hamas while Pakistan’s Inter-Services Intelligence Agency (ISI) supports Jaish-e-Muhammad (JeM),[62] the Afghan Taliban, and Tehrik-i-Taliban Pakistan (the Pakistani Taliban), among others.[63] Terrorists began shifting away from state sponsorship and converging with crime before and during the Cold War, such as the Tamil Tigers who perceived state sponsorship as inconsistent – diversifying their financing through, inter alia, criminal activities and associations.[64] This denotes the problem-solving innovation driver.
The crime-terror convergence exacerbated and galvanised amidst the Soviet Union’s collapse, a pertinent exogeneous force in terrorist financing innovation. Exemplifying opportunity innovation drivers, the deregulation of economic barriers, proliferation of cheap black-market arms, and decreasing number of “consolidated states”[65] facilitated the fusion of the terrorist economy with illicit, criminal economies.[66] This $500 billion “New Economy of Terror” was one-third legal activities like zakat donations or salaries and two-thirds criminal and illegal activities, with drug trafficking being the most profitable.[67] Moreover, the post-1991 era influenced tactical innovations (e.g., illicit activities like internet fraud), strategic innovations[68] and organisational innovations (i.e., decentralisation and criminal associations; Napoleoni, 2014). Additionally, States cannot domestically or internationally justify sponsorship in the new post-1991 paradigm, driving terrorists further towards alternative revenue streams (i.e., a problem-solving innovation driver).[69]
After 9/11, international law enforcement’s pressures on terrorist’s external support revenues[70] intensified terrorist diversification into alternative revenue streams, particularly organised crime.[71] Concurrent pressures on criminal and terrorist organisations also caused the decentralisation of organisational structures.[72] Decentralisation is mutually inclusive to both the War on Drugs and the War on Terror. For example, kinetic operations against AQ led to the death of many of its high-ranking members in its command-and-control structure.[73] Subsequently, AQ adopted the “centralization of decision and decentralization of execution,” with Usama bin Laden (UBL) transitioning from entrepreneurial micromanaging to an inspirational role.[74] The PIRA previously decentralised in the 1970s because of pressures from British law enforcement. It adopted autonomous “family” cell structures. Thus, to maintain operational effectiveness, post-9/11 AQ might have creatively imitated PIRA cell structures, or likewise creatively imitated Baader-Meinhof and ETA cell structures.[75] The “flattening” of terrorist and criminal organisations allows for “synergistic ties” between low and mid-level criminals and terrorists, denoting Moghadam’s integrative driver of innovation (see Figure 1).[76]
Terrorist and criminal organisational adaptions to law enforcement pressures caused organisations to retain a weakened hierarchy with little control over a decentralised network of cells.[77] These autonomous cells became localised and were forced to self-finance, with no “terrorist bank,”[78] but are less constrained by top-down leadership. This enables Mafiosi or cartel cells to cooperate with terrorist organisations, which was previously inhibited because of security and legitimacy concerns.[79] These structural changes mirror legitimate businesses’ organisational innovations, which may suggest globalisation as a main organisational innovation driver.[80]
Additionally, these “synergistic ties” enables, what Chesbrough and colleagues refers to as, open innovation, namely “purposive inflows and outflows of knowledge to accelerate internal innovation.”[81] Prior to 9/11, UBL realised the need for internal and external ideas – demonstrated by Khaled Sheikh Muhammad’s (KSM) contribution to 9/11 as an “independent jihadi entrepreneur.”[82] Likewise, these changes in group structure[83] and ways in which terrorists’ political ends are related to these criminal means[84] enabled tacit and explicit knowledge transfers. These synergistic ties empower low- and mid-level members,[85] reflecting a new-market disruption whereby new integrative innovative structures (decentralisation) target needs (low/mid-level members) that were previously unseen.[86]
Figure 1 Dishman’s (2005) Perception of Crime-Terror Nexus[87]
Terrorist Innovation in the Crime-Terror Nexus
This section merges Tamara Makarenko’s crime-terror convergence and continuum,[88] and terrorist innovation typologies. Transnational crime and terrorism exist on a continuum. The alternative representation of the crime-terror continuum (Figure 2) examines terrorist financing innovation at three separate measures of convergence with criminality. The three discernible categories are alliances, in-house criminal activities, and convergence. Criminal organisation’s measure of convergence with terrorism was excluded in Figure 2 and will not be explored in this paper.
Figure 2 Terrorist Aspect of the Crime-Terror Continuum[89]
Each category of criminal association is a re-conceptualisation of strategy, altering how means relates to its political ends, and thus these strategic innovations occur less often.[90] Moreover, alliances or “External Convergence” constitutes different goals and means of reaching them than In-House Criminal Activities. Strategic re-conceptualisations may manifest different tactical innovations, or “changes in method or operations,”[91] but these are not always mutually exclusive. Lastly, there are separate organisational innovations, or changes in group structures and institutions, in each category. There are also various levels and drivers of innovation within each category.
Alliances/External Convergence: Alliances with Criminal Organisations
Alliances or “External Convergence” are “one-spot” arrangements, or temporary/long-term alliances, with many being predatory or patron-client relationships, between terrorists and criminals.[92] All feature various forms of terrorist financing innovation.
“One-spot” arrangements are mainly driven by problem-solving pressures and insufficient organisational capital.[93] One-off knowledge exchanges exemplify these arrangements. Terrorists may provide bomb-making skills for a fee to criminals, representing a commodification of tacit knowledge exchange, and thus a financial tactical innovation. For example, Pablo Escobar hired the ELN to plant car bombs for a fee.[94]
Terrorists have predatorially extorted drug traffickers for protection money, such as in Afghanistan, West Africa, and Ireland.[95] Patron-client relations is exemplified by Al-Shabaab’s role as a broker between poachers and buyers of ivory.[96] These predatory and patron-client exchanges represent new terrorist financing methods (i.e., technical innovations). Yet, alliances may be driven by opportunity[97] like IS tactical and strategic innovation to manufacture and traffic “Captagon,” a synthetic stimulant fenethylline, capitalising on opportunities provided by Western users and the COVID-19 pandemic that has inhibited European production and distribution of synthetic drugs. Albeit all €1 billion in pills being seized, this represents a new method of financing – a re-conceptualised strategy that incorporates selling drugs as a means to raise funds for IS political aims and required a structural change to incorporate drug production. This was contingent on alliances with a “consortium” of criminal organisations.[98] Denoting the “Balloon Effect” and effects of exogeneous pressures, the Captagon drug seizure by Italian authorities displays how IS has underwent significant tactical, strategic, and organisational innovations amidst COVID-19 and multilateral kinetic operations on ISIS-Core. Similarly, the FARC entered long-term alliances with foreign criminal organisation, like Mexican drug-traffickers, to finance arms purchases with cocaine. These alliances also involve other various high-end commodities, such as weapons and human cargo.[99]
Operational Motivation: Financing through In-House Criminal Activities
Only organisations with enough operational capital may develop “in-house” criminal capabilities.[100] Organisational capital, opportunity, ideology, and security[101] play an integral part in this category.[102] Through organisational learning, terrorists may avert risks involved in cooperation (alliances) by learning in-house capabilities[103]. These risks are associated predominantly with security and risk, two of the six financing criteria listed by Freeman, which are generalised as innovation inhibiting factors. This assumes that associating with criminal organisations is the only means of terrorist financing innovation. Yet, the other aspect of the crime-terror nexus is the in-group criminal activities used to finance terror. Thus, the crime-terror nexus presumes that terrorist organisation’s learned in-house capabilities, suggesting Freeman’s six criteria could be repurposed as innovation drivers. Organisations learning in-house capabilities are exemplified by Jamaah Islamiyah (JI) and the PIRA.
Small scale development of in-house capabilities was demonstrated by JI’s financing of the 2003 Bali bombing. After receiving insufficient external financing, for example from AQ cash injections and charities, JI tactically innovated by relying on criminal activities, including robbing a gold shop in Serang, Java. This enabled JI to finance the bomb-making materials, albeit little-by-little.[104] JI displays small-scale development of criminal activities that do not compare to organisational learning from larger groups like Hezbollah, FARC, or the PIRA.
PIRA adjusted to declining donations in the 1970s by learning and engaging in fraud, smuggling, extortion, and robberies. The PIRA is an archetypal in the latter.[105] After two amateur robberies left large sums of cash behind in 1981, the PIRA learned about the insufficiencies of its Southern Command through a profit-and-loss measurement that mirrored legitimate businesses. The lessons-learned mechanism was an internal source that used direct experience to acquire information, determine the value, and identify improved terrorist financing methods. PIRA interpreted the internally developed knowledge and recognised the need for tactical and organisational innovation and certain tacit knowledge. It developed a specifically trained unit for robberies and recruited lawyers, accountants, and computer experts to secure its finances.[106] The PIRA, thus, carried out organisational learning, as described by Jackson and colleagues.[107] It is successfully carried out all four component processes – acquisition, interpretation, distribution, and storage. Distribution and storage are not mentioned but are self-evident in wide-spread adoption of these lessons learned.[108] These measures maximised the PIRA’s efficiency in the crime-terror nexus.
In addition, driven to organisationally learn and tactically innovate during the Lebanese Civil War, Hezbollah, with its other means of financing destroyed, learned to grow marijuana in the Bekaa Valley.[109] This demonstrates the problem-solving innovation driver. Though, these efforts were uninhibited because of southern Lebanon’s “limited statehood,” denoting Hezbollah ability to recognise and capitalise on new opportunities.[110] Influenced by prospects of growing organisational capital, aforementioned opportunity, and security concerns, Hezbollah strove to improve its financing capabilities while reducing its dependency on external sources.[111] This explains Hezbollah’s reported expansion of its in-house criminal activities to include cultivating poppy crop and processing cocaine, heroin, and hashish in the Bekaa Valley.[112]
Convergence: Criminal Terrorist Hybrid Organisations
“Convergence” is either (a) when a terrorist organisation’s criminal adaptations cause it to appear as both a criminal and terrorist organisation,[113] or (b) when terrorists strategically adapt to criminality to a point in which the new goal becomes self-enrichment while political rhetoric becomes a façade for criminal activities.[114] Hezbollah exemplifies the former and, the Caucasus Emirate (CE), the latter. Both are driven by opportunity and arguably ideology.
The convergence provides a new tactical method: terrorist cells operating in criminal networks. For example, Hezbollah’s cells smuggled pseudoephedrine (needed for methamphetamines) from Canada with Mexican drug dealers.[115] Hezbollah “double[s] as global criminals” as its cells tactically innovate by smuggling cigarettes, laundering money, and counterfeiting to finance terror but remain politically tethered.[116] However, the unprecedented revenue accumulated could have been used to finance an attack. This is disruptive innovation, as extensive criminal cooperation may operationalise previously fiscally-inhibited cells. If Ramzi Yousef’s cell were involved in such arrangements, it may have toppled the World Trade Center with adequately sized ordinance.[117]
Additionally, Hezbollah radically, strategically, and religiously innovated by using a fatwa to legitimise the drug trade. They radically use fatwas to overcomes legitimacy doubts,[118] which might be perceived as a strategic re-conceptualisation of terrorism in how Hezbollah’s means (drug producing and trafficking) connects to its struggle against Israel.[119] Thus, this is an amalgam of strategic and religious innovation that was not previously done. AQ seemingly duplicated[120] this innovation to legitimise the use of drug money to finance the 2004 Madrid bombing.[121] In contrast, the PIRA did not innovate, began losing political capital, and, therefore, had to disassociate with the drug trade.[122]
The Caucasus Emirate’s (CE) recent developments represent the second form of convergence. As a member of AQ’s global jihad, CE similarly decentralised and localised.[123] This also refers to Cheung and colleagues’ creative imitation, the second of seven categories of imitation and innovation.[124] CE creatively imitated AQ’s cell structures, but seemingly possessed different operational features like more extensive cooperation between cells.[125] They were “territorially fragmented network with a flexible hierarchy.”[126] CE delegated financing, recruiting, and operating responsibilities to the jamaats, while seemingly merging AQ’s “centralization of decision and decentralization of execution” with a mountain dweller Muslim solidarity.[127] Nevertheless, decentralised jamaats (cells), with no support from the centre, tactically innovated by cooperating with criminal networks to extort money from locals. Certain jamaats began evolving into extremely violent criminals – shifting from political objectives to personal enrichment.[128]
Conclusion
This paper’s application of crime-terror nexus, as the result of and arena for terrorist financing innovation, rejects dichotomous characterisations of criminal and terrorist organisations. Criminals nor terrorists are homogenous groups.[129] The learning competition between CTF and AML forces and terrorists created a trend that has led to this $500 billion “New Economy of Terror.” The decentralisation of traditional hierarchies and empowerment of low- and mid-level criminals and terrorists has eroded various criteria that inhibited crime-terror cooperation. Thus, terrorists remain with more money to execute their political aims. In contrasting Yousef’s cell with 9/11, financial capital evidently attributes to terrorism’s political consequence. So, as terrorists effectively improve their criminal abilities and associations, criminally enriched terrorism presents a clear and present danger to international security. Yet, to “follow the money, devalue the money, seize the money, and kill the money,” as it pertains to the crime-terror nexus, states must innovatively combat criminal organisations associated with terror as terrorists, especially if it relates to narco-terrorism.
APPENDIX I
Categorisation of Terrorist Financing Sources[130]
APPENDIX II
Crime-Terror Continuum[131]
Bibliography
This paper uses lectures from and personal interactions with Dr Gil-Ad Ariely.
Gil-Ad Ariely, “Terrorism and Counter-Terrorism Innovation,” (course, Interdisciplinary Center Herzliya, Herzliya, Israel, 2020).
“Captagon: Italy seizes €1bn of amphetamines ‘made to fund IS’.” British Broadcasting Corporation (BBC). 1 July, 2020. https://www.bbc.com/news/world-europe-53254879
Chesbrough, Henry, Wim Vanhaverbeke, and Joel West, eds. Open innovation: Researching
a New Paradigm. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006.
Cheung, Tai Ming, Thomas G. Mahnken, and Andrew L. Ross. "Frameworks for analyzing
Chinese defense and military innovation." SITC 2011, no. Policy Brief 27 (2011). https://escholarship.org/uc/item/5cr8j76s.
Christensen, Clayton M. The innovator's dilemma: The revolutionary book that will change
the way you do business. New York, NY: Harper Business Essentials, 2003.
_____. The Innovator's Solution: Creating and Sustaining Successful Growth. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School, 2003.
Commission on Terrorist Attacks upon the United States. "The 9/11 Commission Report:
Final Report of the National Commission on Terrorist Attacks Upon the United States (9/11 Report)". Government. National Commission on Terrorist Attacks Upon the United States, July 22, 2004. https://govinfo.library.unt.edu/911/report/911Report.pdf.
Crenshaw, Martha. “Innovation: Decision Points in the Trajectory of Terrorism,” in Terrorist
Innovations in Weapons of Mass Effect: Preconditions, Causes, and Predictive
Indicators (Workshop Report; Report No. ASCO 2010-01), edited by Maria J.
Rasmussen & Mohammed M. Hafez, 35-50. Ft. Belvoir, VA: The Defense Threat
Reduction Agency Advanced Systems and Concepts Office., 2010
Crenshaw, Martha. “Introduction: Definitions, Approaches, Responses, and Trajectories.” In Explaining Terrorism: Causes, Processes and Consequences, 1-18. Oxford, UK and New York, NY: Routledge, 2011.
Darshan-Leitner, Nitsana., and Samuel M. Katz. Harpoon: Inside the Covert War Against Terrorism’s Money Masters. Paris, France: Hachette Books, 2017.
Dishman, Chris. "Terrorism, crime, and transformation." Studies in Conflict and
Terrorism 24, no. 1 (2001): 43-58.
______. “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge.” Studies in
Conflict & Terrorism 28, no. 3 (2005): 237-252. doi:10.1080/10576100590928124
“Disruptive Innovations.” Clayton Christensen Institute, 2022. Accessed July 29, 2020,
https://www.christenseninstitute.org/disruptive-innovations/.
“‘Disruptive innovation’ theory often misunderstood, says creator Clayton Christensen,”
Canada Broadcasting Corporation Radio (CBC Radio). November 08, 2016. https://www.cbc.ca/radio/thecurrent/the-current-for-november-8-2016-1.3840044/disruptive-innovation-theory-oftenmisunderstood-says-creator-clayton-christensen-1.3840127.
Dolnik, Adam. Understanding Terrorist Innovation: Technology, Tactics, and Global
Trends. London: Routledge, 2007.
Enders, Walter, Todd Sandler, and Khusrav Gaibulloev. "Domestic versus transnational
terrorism: Data, decomposition, and dynamics." Journal of Peace Research48, no. 3 (2011): 319-337. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022343311398926
European Monitoring Centre for Drugs and Drug Addiction (EMCDDA). Estimating the size of the main illicit retail drug markets in Europe: an update (Technical report). Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, December 2019.
Farrell, Theo. “Introduction: Military Adaptation in War.” In Military Adaptation in Afghanistan edited by Theo Farrell, Frans Osinga, & James A. Russell, 1-23. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2013.
FATF. Financial Action Task Force: Trade Based Money Laundering, Paris: FATF, 2006.
https://www.fatf-gafi.org/publications/methodsandtrends/documents/trade-basedmoneylaundering.html
_____. Emerging Terrorist Financing Risks, Paris: FATF, 2015.
www.fatf-gafi.org/publications/methodsandtrends/documents/emerging-terrorist-financing-risks.html
______. The Financial Action Task Force (FATF), 2020. Retrieved July 30, 2020, https://www.fatf-gafi.org/
Foreign Terrorists in America: Five Years After the World Trade Center, Before Senate
Judiciary Committee, Subcommittee on Technology, Terrorism, and Government
Information, 105th Cong. (1998) (statements by J. Gilmore Childers, Esq. and Henry J. DePippo, Esq.). https://irp.fas.org/congress/1998_hr/s980224c.htm.
Freeman, Michael. “Introduction to Financing Terrorism: Case Studies” In Financing
Terrorism: Case Studies, edited by Michael Freeman, 3-6. Farnham: Taylor & Francis Group, 2012.
______. “Sources of Terrorist Financing: Theory and Typology.” In Financing Terrorism:
Case Studies, edited by Michael Freeman, 7-25. Farnham: Taylor & Francis Group, 2012.
Freeman, Michael, and Moyara Ruehsen. “Terrorism Financing Methods: An
Overview.” Perspectives on Terrorism 7, no. 4 (2013): 5-26. Accessed August 10, 2020. www.jstor.org/stable/26296981
Ganor, Boaz. “Captagon: The drug that funds and fuels terrorist groups,” interviewed by James Morrow, Australian Broadcasting Corporation (ABC). July 12, 2020. https://www.abc.net.au/radionational/programs/sundayextra/captagon:-the-drug-that-funds-and-fuels-terrorist-groups/12435550?fbclid=IwAR1q78Kop3pOJ5-s4dHE4ygmKpg_E3lWIxmc3Klu_efE00epq4L4-IKzGdI
This is the interview of Boaz Ganor regarding the Italian police seizure of 14 tonnes of Captagon.
______. “Defining Terrorism: Is One Man's Terrorist another Man's Freedom Fighter?” Police Practice and Research 3, no. 4 (2002): 287-304. doi:10.1080/1561426022000032060
Ganor, Boaz, and Miri Halperin Wernli. “The infiltration of terrorist organizations into the
pharmaceutical industry: Hezbollah as a case study.” Studies in Conflict &
Terrorism 36, no. 9 (2013): 699-712.
Hoffman, Bruce. “Terrorist targeting: Tactics, trends, and potentialities.” Terrorism and Political Violence 5, no. 2 (1993): 12-29. doi:10.1080/09546559308427205
_____. Inside terrorism. New York City, NY: Columbia University Press, 1998.
Jackson, Brian A., John C. Baker, Kim Cragin, John Parachini, Horacio R. Trujillo and Peter
Chalk. Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation (MG-331-NIJ), 2005. As of August 02, 2020: https://www.rand.org/pubs/monographs/MG331.html
_____ . Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 2: Case Studies of Organizational Learning in Five
Terrorist Groups, Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation (MG-332-NIJ), 2005. As of August 02, 2020: https://www.rand.org/pubs/monographs/MG332.html
Jacobson, Michael. “Terrorist financing and the Internet.” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 33,
no. 4 (2010): 353-363.
Kambere, Geoffrey, Puay Hock Goh, Pranav Kumar, and Fulgence Msafiri. “Lashkar-e-Taiba
(LeT).” In Financing Terrorism: Case Studies, edited by Michael Freeman, 75-92. Farnham: Taylor & Francis Group, 2012.
Keetly, Mick. “Closing the Circle - The AFP's capacity to fight terrorism.” Platypus: Journal of the Australian Federal Police, no. 78 (2003): 4-10.
LaFree, Gary, and Laura Dugan. “Introducing the global terrorism database.” Terrorism and
Political Violence 19, no. 2 (2007): 181-204.
Levitt, Matthew. “Charitable and Humanitarian Organizations in the Network of
International Terrorist Financing.” The Washington Institute, published on August 1, 2002. https://www.washingtoninstitute.org/policy-analysis/view/charitable-and-humanitarian-organizations-in-the-network-of-international-t
_____ . “Hezbollah finances: Funding the party of God.” In Terrorism Financing and State
Responses: A Comparative Perspective, edited by Jeanne K. Giraldo, Harold A.
Trinkunas, 134-151. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2007.
Levy, Ido, and Abdi Yusuf. “How do terrorist organizations make money? Terrorist funding
and innovation in the case of Al-Shabaab.” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 44, no. 12
(2021): 1167-1189. doi:10.1080/1057610X.2019.1628622
Makarenko, Tamara. "The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between
transnational organised crime and terrorism." Global crime 6, no. 1 (2004): 129-145. doi:10.1080/1744057042000297025
Moghadam, Assaf. “How Al Qaeda Innovates.” Security Studies 22, no. 3 (2013): 466-497. doi:10.1080/09636412.2013.816123
Napoleoni, Loretta. Terrorism and the Economy: How the War on Terror Is Bankrupting the World: Vol. Unabridged. Seven Stories Press, 2014.
Neumann, Peter. R. “Don’t Follow the Money: The Problem with the War on Terrorist
Financing.” Foreign Affairs (July/August 2017).
https://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/2017-06-13/dont-follow-money
O’Callaghan, Sean, The Informer, London, UK: Corgi Books, 1999.
Oftedal, Emilie. The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe: A New Report (Rep.). Kjeller, Norway: Norwegian Defence Research Establishment (FFI), 2015.
Riedel, Bruce. O. Deadly Embrace: Pakistan, America, and the Future of the Global
Jihad (2nd ed.). Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 2012.
Risse, Thomas. “Governance in Areas of Limited Statehood: Introduction and Overview,” in
Governance Without a State?: Policies and Politics in Areas of Limited Statehood, edited by Thomas Risse, 1-35. New York: Columbia University Press, 2011. doi:10.7312/riss15120
Schumpeter, Joseph. A. The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits,
Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle. New Brunswick: Transaction, 1934.
Souleimanov, Emil. “The Caucasus emirate: Genealogy of an Islamist insurgency.” Middle
East Policy 18, no. 4 (2011): 155-168. doi:10.1111/j.1475-4967.2011.00517.x
Thanawala, Kishor. “Schumpeter's theory of economic development and development
economics.” Review of Social Economy 52, no. 4 (1994): 353-363. doi:10.1080/758523329
US Department of the Army, Headquarters. Counterinsurgency. US Army Field
Manual 3-24/Marine Corps Warfighting Publication 3-33.5. Washington, DC: US Department of the Army (2006).
U.S. House, Committee on Foreign Affairs. Attacking Hezbollah's Financial Network: Policy Options (E. R. Royce) [H.R. Doc. 115-51 from 115th Cong., 1st sess.]. Washington, D.C.: US Government Publishing Office, 2017.
Windle, James. “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism.” In Routledge
Handbook of Terrorism and Counterterrorism, edited by Silke Andrew, 195-206.
New York: Routledge, 2019.
Zabyelina, Yuliya. “The Industry of Terror: Criminal Financing of the North Caucasus
Insurgency,” in Terrorist Criminal Enterprises: Financing Terrorism through
Organized Crime, edited by Kimberley L. Thachuk and Rollie Lal, 63-78. Santa
Barbara, Calif.: Praeger Security International, 2018.
http://publisher.abc-clio.com/9781440860683
Notes
[1] Boaz Ganor, “Defining Terrorism: Is One Man's Terrorist another Man's Freedom Fighter?” Police Practice and Research 3, no. 4 (2002): 295.
[2] This number was calculated in 2020. See Boaz Ganor, “Defining Terrorism: Is One Man's Terrorist another Man's Freedom Fighter?” Police Practice and Research 3, no. 4 (2002), 287-304; Enders, Walter, Todd Sandler, and Khusrav Gaibulloev. "Domestic versus transnational terrorism: Data, decomposition, and dynamics." Journal of Peace Research48, no. 3 (2011): 319-337; Gary LaFree and Laura Dugan, “Introducing the global terrorism database,” Terrorism and Political Violence 19, no. 2 (2007): 181-204.
[3] Assaf Moghadam, “How Al Qaeda Innovates,” Security Studies 22, no. 3 (2013), 467.
[4] See “Disruptive Innovations,” Clayton Christensen Institute, 2022. Accessed July 29, 2020,
https://www.christenseninstitute.org/disruptive-innovations/.
[5] Michael Freeman, “Introduction to Financing Terrorism: Case Studies,” in Financing Terrorism: Case Studies, ed. by Michael Freeman (Farnham: Taylor & Francis Group, 2012), 5.
[6] Nitsana Darshan-Leitner and Samuel M. Katz. Harpoon: Inside the Covert War Against Terrorism’s Money Masters. Paris, France: Hachette Books, 2017. See esp. Preface, “High-Value Targets.”
[7] Ibid.
[8] See Tamara Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” Global crime 6, no. 1 (2004): 129-145.
[9] See Darshan-Leitner and Katz, Harpoon: Inside the Covert War Against Terrorism’s Money Masters.
[10] Michael Freeman, “Sources of Terrorist Financing: Theory and Typology,” in Financing Terrorism: Case Studies, ed. by Michael Freeman (Farnham: Taylor & Francis Group, 2012), 8-9.
[11] The “Balloon Effect” describes when pressure is exerted in one place and causes the air or flow to move to an area of least resistance.
[12] For example, taxing the drug trade or financing through credit card fraud.
[13] Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” 130.
[14] Freeman, Financing Terrorism: Case Studies, 9-12.
[15] European Monitoring Centre for Drugs and Drug Addiction (EMCDDA). Estimating the size of the main illicit retail drug markets in Europe: an update (Technical report) (Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union, December 2019), 34.
[16] In other words, terrorists desire predictability and consistency.
[17] Though, exogeneous pressures may inhibit these simplistic measures, forcing terrorist to learn and adopt less simplistic methods.
[18] See Freeman, “Sources of Terrorist Financing: Theory and Typology,” 9-12. This provides further detail on these criteria.
[19] See Michael Freeman, “Sources of Terrorist Financing: Theory and Typology”; Peter. R. Neumann, “Don’t Follow the Money: The Problem with the War on Terrorist Financing,” Foreign Affairs (July/August 2017); FATF, Emerging Terrorist Financing Risks (Paris: FATF, 2015); Emilie Oftedal, The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe: A New Report (Rep.) (Kjeller, Norway: Norwegian Defence Research Establishment [or Forsvarets
Forskningsinstitutt, FFI], 2015).
[20] Michael Freeman, “Sources of Terrorist Financing: Theory and Typology,” 12-22.
[21] See Neumann, “Don’t Follow the Money: The Problem with the War on Terrorist Financing.”
[22] FATF, The Financial Action Task Force (FATF), 2020.
[23] FATF, Emerging Terrorist Financing Risks (Paris: FATF, 2015), 13-20.
[24] Emilie Oftedal, The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe, 19-21, 26-27, 53.
[25] Oftedal, The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe, 53, note 173; Oftedal argues that loans and credit card debt should be classified as legal activity, as it is counterintuitive to categorise a legal loan with drug smuggling. However, as terrorists have no intention to pay it back, it is arguably an illegal activity.
[26] Oftedal, The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe, 11-13, 53; see also Appendix I.
[27] Oftedal, The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe, 11-13; FATF, Emerging Terrorist Financing Risks (Paris: FATF, 2015); see also Ido Levy and Abdi Yusuf, “How do terrorist organizations make money? Terrorist funding and innovation in the case of Al-Shabaab,” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 44, no. 12 (2021): 1167-1189.
[28] Geoffrey Kambere, Puay Hock Goh, Pranav Kumar, and Fulgence Msafiri, “Lashkar-e-Taiba (LeT),” in Financing Terrorism: Case Studies, ed. by Michael Freeman (Farnham: Taylor & Francis Group, 2012), 87; Michael Freeman and Moyara Ruehsen, “Terrorism Financing Methods: An Overview,” Perspectives on Terrorism 7, no. 4 (2013): 12-13; Oftedal, The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe, 13.
[29] See FATF. Financial Action Task Force: Trade Based Money Laundering (Paris: FATF, 2006), 3. For example, money laundering is conducted through misrepresentations in products’ quality, quantity and/or price.
[30] Oftedal, The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe, 13; see also Michael Jacobson, “Terrorist financing and the Internet,” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 33, no. 4 (2010): 353-363.
[31] US Department of the Army, Headquarters. Counterinsurgency. US Army Field Manual 3-24/Marine Corps Warfighting Publication 3-33.5 (Washington, DC: US Department of the Army, 2006), xi.
[32] This section uses lectures from and personal interactions with Dr Gil-Ad Ariely.
[33]Adam Dolnik, Understanding Terrorist Innovation: Technology, Tactics, and Global
Trends (London: Routledge, 2007), 69; Bruce Hoffman, “Terrorist targeting: Tactics, trends, and potentialities,” Terrorism and Political Violence 5, no. 2 (1993): 12-29. Bruce Hoffman, Inside terrorism (New York City, NY: Columbia University Press, 1998). It should be noted that Hoffman has since changed this view.
[34] Martha Crenshaw, “Introduction: Definitions, Approaches, Responses, and Trajectories,” in Explaining Terrorism: Causes, Processes and Consequences (Oxford, UK and New York, NY: Routledge, 2011), 36.
[35] See Joseph. A. Schumpeter, The Theory of Economic Development: An Inquiry into Profits, Capital, Credit, Interest, and the Business Cycle (New Brunswick: Transaction, 1934).
[36] Schumpeter, The Theory of Economic Development, 65-66.
[37] Schumpeter, The Theory of Economic Development, 66; See also Kishor Thanawala, “Schumpeter's theory of economic development and development economics,” Review of Social Economy 52, no. 4 (1994): 353-363. Thanawala’s work provides an essential overview of key concepts of Schumpeter’s economic development posit.
[38] Ido Levy and Abdi Yusuf, “How do terrorist organizations make money? Terrorist funding and innovation in the case of Al-Shabaab,” 4.
[39] Dolnik, Understanding Terrorist Innovation: Technology, Tactics, and Global Trends, 6.
[40] Ibid.
[41] Martha Crenshaw, “Innovation: Decision Points in the Trajectory of Terrorism,” in Terrorist Innovations in Weapons of Mass Effect: Preconditions, Causes, and Predictive Indicators (Workshop Report; Report No. ASCO 2010-01), ed. by Maria J. Rasmussen & Mohammed M. Hafez (Ft. Belvoir, VA: The Defense Threat Reduction Agency Advanced Systems and Concepts Office, 2010), 36-41.
[42] Crenshaw, “Introduction: Definitions, Approaches, Responses, and Trajectories,” 6.
[43] Crenshaw, “Innovation: Decision Points in the Trajectory of Terrorism,” 38.
[44] Ibid, 39.
[45] Ibid, 40.
[46] See Moghadam, “How Al Qaeda Innovates.”
[47] Moghadam, “How Al Qaeda Innovates,” 473-4.
[48] Ibid, 489.
[49] Ibid, 484. According to Moghadam, this is originally from Khalid al-Hammadi, “The Inside Story of al-Qa’ida, Part 4,” Al-Quds al-Arabi (22 March 2005). He used this source in his analysis of al Qaeda leading up to the 9/11 attacks.
[50] Ibid, 472.
[51] Loretta Napoleoni, Terrorism and the Economy: How the War on Terror Is Bankrupting the World: Vol. Unabridged (Seven Stories Press, 2014), 65.
[52] Clayton M. Christensen, The innovator's dilemma: The revolutionary book that will change the way you do business (New York, NY: Harper Business Essentials, 2003); Tai Ming Cheung, Thomas G. Mahnken, and Andrew L. Ross, “Frameworks for analyzing Chinese defense and military innovation,” SITC 2011, no. Policy Brief 27 (2011).
[53] Clayton M. Christensen, The Innovator's Solution: Creating and Sustaining Successful Growth (Boston, MA: Harvard Business School, 2003); See also “Disruptive Innovations,” Clayton Christensen Institute, 2022. Accessed July 29, 2020, https://www.christenseninstitute.org/disruptive-innovations/.
[54] “'Disruptive innovation' theory often misunderstood, says creator Clayton Christensen,” Canada Broadcasting Corporation Radio (CBC Radio). November 08, 2016. https://www.cbc.ca/radio/thecurrent/the-current-for-november-8-2016-1.3840044/disruptive-innovation-theory-oftenmisunderstood-says-creator-clayton-christensen-1.3840127.
[55] Cheung, Mahnken, and Ross, “Frameworks for analyzing Chinese defense and military innovation,” 3.
[56] Theo Farrell, “Introduction: Military Adaptation in War” in Military Adaptation in Afghanistan ed. by Theo Farrell, Frans Osinga, and James A. Russell (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2013), 7.
[57] Learning competition was previously defined by U.S. Army Manual 3-24 (2006).
[58] Brian A. Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism (Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation MG-331-NIJ, 2005), 11-14, 30.
[59] Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism, 14.
[60] Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism, 15.
[61] Freeman, “Sources of Terrorist Financing: Theory and Typology,” 13.
[62] Bruce Riedel, O. Deadly Embrace: Pakistan, America, and the Future of the Global Jihad (2nd ed.) (Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, 2012), 59, 69, 73; It is reported that Pakistan’s ISI created and maintained ties with Jaish-e-Muhammad as an asymmetric means of attacking India.
[63] Freeman, “Sources of Terrorist Financing: Theory and Typology,” 13; Reidal, 2011)
[64] James Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” in Routledge Handbook of Terrorism and Counterterrorism, ed. by Silke Andrew (New York and London: Routledge, 2019), 199, 195-206.
[65] Thomas Risse, “Governance in Areas of Limited Statehood: Introduction and Overview,” in Governance Without a State?: Policies and Politics in Areas of Limited Statehood, ed. by Thomas Risse (New York: Columbia University Press, 2011), 5.
[66] Napoleoni, Terrorism and the Economy, 65; Risse, “Governance in Areas of Limited Statehood: Introduction and Overview,” 1-35.
[67] Napoleoni, Terrorism and the Economy, 65; Thus, narco-terrorism is featured heavily in this paper.
[68] This refers to a general re-conceptualising of criminal means so they would relate to the political ends of terrorist organisations.
[69] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 198; This denotes another instance of problem-solving pressure driving innovation, namely self-financing, which encompasses numerous tactical innovations.
[70] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 198. This refers to “External Support” as defined by the FFI and FATF terrorist financing typologies. Windle perceives these sources as specifically State sponsorship, charities, and individual donations.
[71] See Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 198-199; Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism.”
[72] See Chris Dishman. "Terrorism, crime, and transformation." Studies in Conflict and Terrorism 24, no. 1 (2001); Chris Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 28, no. 3 (2005), 237, 243-244.
[73] Ibid.
[74] Ibid, 237, 242.
[75] Brian A. Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 2: Case Studies of Organizational Learning in Five Terrorist Groups (Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND Corporation MG-332-NIJ, 2005), 129-30.
[76] Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 237.
[77] AQ exemplifies this new structural arrangement.
[78] Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 246.
[79] Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 238; Security and legitimacy concerns are two of six of Freeman (2012) six criteria considered when financing terror.
[80] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 199.
[81] Henry Chesbrough, Wim Vanhaverbeke, and Joel West, eds. Open innovation: Researching a New Paradigm. (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2006), 1.
[82] Ibid; Moghadam, “How Al Qaeda Innovates,” 479.
[83] This refers to Crenshaw’s organisational innovation.
[84] This refers to Crenshaw’s structural innovation.
[85] Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 238.
[86] Clayton M. Christensen, The Innovator's Solution: Creating and Sustaining Successful Growth (Boston, MA: Harvard Business School, 2003).
[87] See Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 245.
[88] See Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” 130-131; The crime-terror convergence and continuum are explained further in this work by Makarenko.
[89] Figure 2 is inspired by Makarenko’s (2004) Crime-Terror continuum but seeks to incorporate terrorist innovation theories. Makarenko’s Crime Terror Continuum is seen in the appendix.
[90] Crenshaw, “Innovation: Decision Points in the Trajectory of Terrorism,” 36; see also Crenshaw, “Introduction: Definitions, Approaches, Responses, and Trajectories.”
[91] Crenshaw, “Innovation: Decision Points in the Trajectory of Terrorism,” 39.
[92] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 199, 201; Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” 131; Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 246.
[93] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 199, 201; Moghadam, “How Al Qaeda Innovates,” 472; These are drivers of innovation, as detailed and applied by Assaf Moghadam (2013).
[94] Dishman, "Terrorism, crime, and transformation," 53; see also Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” 131.
[95] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 199-200.
[96] Ibid, 200.
[97] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 200; Napoleoni, Terrorism and the Economy, 65; The opportunity driver of innovation is particularly associated with Napoleoni’s “New Economy of Terror” and descriptions of opportunity provided by Windle.
[98] “Captagon: Italy seizes €1bn of amphetamines 'made to fund IS'.” British Broadcasting Corporation (BBC). 1 July, 2020, https://www.bbc.com/news/world-europe-53254879; Boaz Ganor, “Captagon: The drug that funds and fuels terrorist groups,” interviewed by James Morrow, Australian Broadcasting Corporation (ABC). July 12, 2020, https://www.abc.net.au/radionational/programs/sundayextra/captagon:-the-drug-that-funds-and-fuels-terrorist-groups/12435550?fbclid=IwAR1q78Kop3pOJ5-s4dHE4ygmKpg_E3lWIxmc3Klu_efE00epq4L4-IKzGdI.
[99] Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” 138.
[100] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 200.
[101] When applied to learning in-house criminal activities, security, one of six financing criteria listed by Freeman (2012) that usually inhibits, is repurposed into an innovation driver.
[102] Moghadam, “How Al Qaeda Innovates,” 472; Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism, 19-20.
[103] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 200-201.
[104] Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 2: Case Studies of Organizational Learning in Five Terrorist Groups, 79; Mick Keetly, “Closing the Circle - The AFP's capacity to fight terrorism,” Platypus: Journal of the Australian Federal Police, no. 78 (2003): 4-10.
[105] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 197.
[106] Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism, 9-15; Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 2: Case Studies of Organizational Learning in Five Terrorist Groups, 125-126. See also Sean O’Callaghan, The Informer (London, UK: Corgi Books, 1999), 228. As sourced by Jackson and colleagues (second volume), O’Callaghan even further detail on the “professionalization” of the PIRA.
[107] Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism, 9-15.
[108] Ibid, 11-14, 30.
[109]Boaz Ganor and Miri Halperin Wernli, "The infiltration of terrorist organizations into the pharmaceutical industry: Hezbollah as a case study," Studies in Conflict & Terrorism 36, no. 9 (2013), 702; U.S. House, Committee on Foreign Affairs. Attacking Hezbollah's Financial Network: Policy Options (E. R. Royce) [H.R. Doc. 115-51 from 115th Cong., 1st sess.]. (Washington, D.C.: US Government Publishing Office, 2017), 18, 21; see also Matthew Levitt, “Hezbollah finances: Funding the party of God,” in Terrorism Financing and State Responses: A Comparative Perspective, ed. by Jeanne K. Giraldo, Harold A. Trinkunas (Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, 2007).
[110] Risse, “Governance in Areas of Limited Statehood: Introduction and Overview,” 5; Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism, 19.
[111] Jackson et al., Aptitude for Destruction, Volume 1: Organizational Learning in Terrorist Groups and Its Implications for Combating Terrorism, 19.
[112] Boaz Ganor and Miri Halperin Wernli, "The infiltration of terrorist organizations into the pharmaceutical industry: Hezbollah as a case study,” 702; Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” 135.
[113] This infers that these organisations do not alter their political aims but rather strategically re-conceptualise to a point in which their criminality makes them appear as a criminal and terrorist organisation.
[114] Makarenko, Tamara. “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” 135-138; Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 48.
[115] Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 246.
[116] U.S. House, Attacking Hezbollah's Financial Network: Policy Options, 115-51.
[117] See Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 247; see Foreign Terrorists in America: Five Years After the World Trade Center, Before Senate Judiciary Committee, Subcommittee on Technology, Terrorism, and Government Information, 105th Cong. (1998) (statements by J. Gilmore Childers, Esq., and Henry J. DePippo, Esq.); see also Matthew Levitt, “Charitable and Humanitarian Organizations in the Network of
International Terrorist Financing,” The Washington Institute, published on August 1, 2002; See also Commission on Terrorist Attacks upon the United States. "The 9/11 Commission Report: Final Report of the National Commission on Terrorist Attacks Upon the United States (9/11 Report)” (Government. National Commission on Terrorist Attacks Upon the United States, July 22, 2004), 72-73, 147; Ramzi Yousef wanted to construct a larger bomb for the attack on the World Trade Center in 1993 but had insufficient funds. His bomb, bolstered by sticks of ammonium nitrate dynamite, still killed 6 and injured thousands.
[118] As previously stated, this also constitutes an innovation driver from problem-solving pressures.
[119] Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 247.
[120] See Cheung, Mahnken, and Ross, “Frameworks for analyzing Chinese defense and military innovation,” 3; This refers to Cheung and colleagues’ duplicative imitation, the first of seven categories of imitation and innovation.
[121] See Cheung, Mahnken, and Ross, “Frameworks for analyzing Chinese defense and military innovation.”; Dishman, “The Leaderless Nexus: When Crime and Terror Converge,” 247.
[122] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 198.
[123] Emil Souleimanov, “The Caucasus emirate: Genealogy of an Islamist insurgency,” Middle East Policy 18, no. 4 (2011): 164.
[124] There work describes creative imitation in more detail.
[125] Souleimanov, “The Caucasus emirate,” 161.
[126] Ibid, 164.
[127] Souleimanov, “The Caucasus emirate,” 158.
[128] Yuliya Zabyelina, “The Industry of Terror: Criminal Financing of the North Caucasus Insurgency,” in Terrorist Criminal Enterprises: Financing Terrorism through Organized Crime, ed. by Kimberley L. Thachuk and Rollie Lal (Santa Barbara, Calif.: Praeger Security International, 2018), 174.
[129] Windle, “Fundraising, Organised Crime and Financing Terrorism,” 202.
[130] Oftedal, The Financing of Jihadi Terrorist Cells in Europe, 53.
[131] Makarenko, “The crime-terror continuum: tracing the interplay between transnational organised crime and terrorism,” 130-131.